Resource Efficiency: Concepts, Challenges, Scenarios and Policy Options
"No hay escasez de conceptos que apunten a mostrar cómo nuestra economía puede convertirse en más eficiente en recursos como la eco-Innovación, la cuna a la cuna. Hemos analizado una larga lista de conceptos que utilizan tres dimensiones: el alcance del cambio, la ambición con respecto al grado de cambio (paradigmático) y la existencia de conductores y vías de cambio plausibles. "
Concepts Fostering Resource Efficiency: A Trade-off Between Ambitions and Viability☆
1. Introduction
In the last decade, resource efficiency and the related ambition of creating a circular economy has become a prominent topic on the sustainability agendas of particularly the EU (EC, 2014a), China (State Council, 2013) and Japan (MoE, 2006). More recently, this agenda received support from important societal stakeholders, such as the Ellen MacArthur Foundation (Ellen Macarthur Foundation (EMF), 2012, Ellen Macarthur Foundation (EMF), 2015) and the World Economic Forum (WEF, 2014).
The ambition and scope of such a resource-efficiency and circularity
agenda can be defined in different ways. Some interpretations of
resource-efficiency go as far as to include the ability of nature to
absorb pollution and waste, expanding this agenda to a wide range of
environmental problems (EC, 2005).
For the purpose of this paper, we focus on the efficient use of
resources per se. We include both biotic and abiotic resources (cf. EMF, 2012).
In this context, resource efficiency is usually defined as the useful
material output related to (life cycle) material input (e.g. Dahlstrom and Ekins, 2005), or the monetary value of product/service output related to (life cycle) material input (e.g. EC, 2014a). While the planetary boundaries for resource extraction still need refinement (cf Rockström et al., 2009, Steffen et al., 2015), authors such as EMF (2012) and UNEP (2011) suggest that drastic improvements in resource efficiency are required to enable future economic growth, and/or that absolute reductions of resource use should be pursued. Ellen Macarthur Foundation (EMF), 2012, Ellen Macarthur Foundation (EMF), 2015 calls this a ‘resource revolution’.
In
the last decades, many concepts in the field of sustainability have
been proposed that (amongst others) aim to show how economies can become
more resource-efficient. Examples include industrial ecology, eco-innovation, cradle to cradle,
transition management, beyond GDP, eco-efficiency, and a couple of
dozen others. Some of these concepts, especially the more radical ones
such as de-growth, go beyond resource efficiency in their scale of
envisaged change, but for all of them increased resource efficiency is a
major objective, and therefore the term is used in this paper to
include these concepts as well. One concept, which is more or less
synonymous with resource efficiency, is decoupling, which, in the
formulation of UNEP, 2011, UNEP, 2014a signifies that resource use and/or environmental impacts are
increasing less fast than GDP (relative decoupling) or actually
declining while GDP continues to grow (absolute decoupling). It can be
seen that decoupling is a necessary characteristic of increased
resourced efficiency as defined in the previous paragraph, so that in
the categorisation that follows increased resource efficiency and
decoupling are treated together.
This
paper evaluates the potential of these concepts to guide how to achieve
radical resource-efficiency improvements. For this, the concept must
address broad areas of society, be radical in nature, but, most
importantly, also offer clear guidance as to how incentives for change
can be implemented. Yet, as will be seen, the literature on governance
and transitions suggests that the more extensive and radical the scope
and ambition of change are, the greater will be the systemic and
institutional resistance to change. The evaluation is done via the
following steps:
- •
- Section 2 analyses as background how the literature discusses how momentum for change towards resource-efficiency may be brought about
- •
- Section 3 reviews a number of existing classifications of concepts related to eco-efficiency, sustainability and resource efficiency (including these terms themselves), and derives the analytical framework used in this paper
- •
- Section 4 scores some 30 concepts on the dimensions of this framework
- •
- Section 5 provides a discussion and conclusions.
2. Changes to Circularity and Resource Efficiency – What Factors Create Momentum?
2.1. Factors Creating Resistance to Change
Changes to resource efficiency and
circularity require incentives for the change to take place. Scholars
in the field of innovation and transition management in this context
commonly make a distinction between incremental changes and radical
changes. Incremental changes usually marginally affect the overall
system and are related to relatively limited gains. The potential for
cost reduction by using resources more efficiently often is the main
driver. Such changes however are unlikely to create radical reductions
of resource use in society, nor bring about the overall transition to a circular economy.
The
theory of transition management offers a helpful perspective to
understand what helps and hinders more radical change processes in
society, such as a radical improvement of resource efficiency and the
transition to a circular economy (see e.g. the contributions in Elzen et al., 2004; see also Geels, 2002, Geels, 2005 and Kemp, 2008).
Such transition processes can be evolutionary, where the outcome is not
planned in a significant way, or co-evolutionary and goal-oriented,
where some vision of the end-state is guiding decision makers or
orienting strategic decisions. Most authors analyzing such transition
processes propose to use a multi-level, multi-actor, and multi-phase
concept to describe the process of change or transition (e.g. Rotmans et al., 2001, Elzen et al., 2004, Geels, 2005, Kemp et al., 2007, Loorbach, 2014).
The multi-level concept divides societal systems in three main levels.
- •
- a macro- or landscape level, which is to be taken for granted on short- and medium term. It contains very or fairly stable factors such as geopolitical realities, widely held values, and stable megatrends (e.g. in the area of demography). It poses boundary conditions for the next level (the regime) to evolve, and is hence normally a source of stability (with the exceptions when disruptive shocks at this level occur, such as wars and natural disasters)
- •
- a regime level. The regime itself is an interdependent and co-evolving set of technologies, symbolic meanings, services, consumer practices, rules, financial relations and expectations. It is difficult to change one part without the rest. This dynamic equilibrium changes usually only incrementally. A simple example: you cannot put a hydrogen car on the road without hydrogen gas stations, new safety rules, maybe even new driving licence standards, etc.
- •
- niches, where innovators can try out new consumption and production practices. It is however often difficult for niches to become mainstream, due to the stabilizing effects at regime and landscape level.
The
multi-actor concept metaphorically points at the fact that systems have
to be seen as socio-technical regimes: interrelations of existing
technologies, knowledge, skill sets,
routines, regulatory demands, policy preferences, available
infrastructures, and prevailing cultural and symbolic meanings that
usually cannot be changed independently, but must co-evolve.
The
multi-phase concept stipulates that transitions go through distinct
phases: a pre-development phase in which new practices are tested in
niches, a take-off phase in which elements of the new regime challenge
the old regime and start to break through, a (relatively short)
acceleration phase in which the old regime starts to break down, and a
stabilization phase in which the new regime has taken over. The take-off
phase is crucial for the success of the transition or regime change,
and needs a ‘green light’ at all levels: availability of promising
elements of a new regime in niches, instability in the existing regime,
and a growing incompatibility between regime and landscape.
Transition
theory explains why intentional radical socio-technical change is so
difficult. Both the landscape and regime levels guide developments. This
dynamic equilibrium changes usually only incrementally. But the theory
can also help to find tensions or ‘cracks’ in the system that can make
stimulating changes easier. Such ‘cracks’ can be: internal tensions in
the production-consumption regime, or misfit between regime and
landscape, and can have a normative and operational dimension. Examples
include a production structure evidently based on labor exploitations in the South (misfit with ethical meta-values), or a sector practising agriculture in greenhouses, that due to rising energy prices becomes too expensive (operational misfit).
When
promising niches are available that have matured (deepened) and got
connected (broadened), and at the same time ‘cracks’ develop or ‘shocks’
in the landscape occur, pressure on the regime may become so high that
rapid change may become possible (niches ‘scaling up’). The regime
breaks down, and niches plus the remnants of the existing regime will
develop new structures, which eventually will stabilise and form a new
regime (cf. Geels, 2005, Kemp and van den Bosch, 2006).
2.2. Options for Intentionally Guiding Change
We
can roughly identify three approaches by which transitions can be
stimulated – in our case the one to a resource efficient economy.1
First, one can rely largely on market based instruments. The World Business Council for Sustainable Development (WBCSD),
probably the most powerful and influential industry think tank on
sustainability, even has a slogan that reflects this: ‘Sustainability
through the market’ (WBCSD, 1999).
The idea is that once perverse subsidies are abolished and the
undesirable side-effects of our current production and consumption
systems are internalized into the market prices, the market mechanisms will
direct innovations in the correct, sustainable direction. This
approach, using mainly market-based instruments is useful if one knows
which changes to the market incentive system will change the behaviour
of actors in the direction of more sustainability. The exact means or
roadmap to the sustainability goal can in principle still be uncertain.
This approach has the following limitations:
- •
- Since this option implies that changes in the rules of the (market) game must be implemented, most importantly internalizing external costs, a party must have the power or legitimacy to make them.
- •
- If there are strong impediments to change that cannot be overcome by financial incentives, this approach will not be effective.
The
second approach relies heavily on top-down government. This type of
approach to transition management is probably supported by those who
call for a ‘master plan’ or ‘Apollo-program’ for saving the environment.
It should consist of an all-encompassing effort with a lead role for
the government in various fields to realize the necessary system
innovations. In more moderate forms, the goals and planning are more
indicative and the assessment of which means to use more participatory,
but there is still a powerful central actor which can when necessary
enforce progress of the process of change. The US space program launched
by President Kennedy is one example. And though at terrible human
costs, both the Soviet Union and China transformed themselves from
mainly agricultural countries into industrial nations via a number of
strong centrally organized 5-year plans, changing the structure and
culture of their society in the process (Kennedy, 1988). This approach can be applied under the following conditions.
- •
- First, there must be a party in the system that has the power or legitimacy to apply a hierarchist governance model.
- •
- Second, it must be fairly clear which transition goals must be reached and which means are the most appropriate to do so. Under these conditions, a top-down planning approach can be an effective and efficient way to realize a transition.
The third approach relies more on bottom-up activities in society of front-runner companies, civil society,
and progressive governments. Scholars representing this view try to
understand how fundamental change can be fostered via ‘radical
incrementalism’, ‘variety and selection’, ‘connecting long term visions
and goals to short-term implementation activities’, and fostering
‘coalitions of the willing’ (e.g., Ostrom, 1990, Rotmans et al., 2001, Hajer, 2011).
The idea is that bottom-up initiatives will experiment with
socio-technical innovations in a domain where a transition is desired,
creating niches of change. Over time, this may lead to a situation where
niches are capable to outcompete mainstream systems via the market
based mechanisms of the first approach, or that gradually more critical mass for policy support for change is created, which then allows to apply the more top-down approaches from the second approach (Tukker and Butter, 2007). Noteworthy initiatives include the World Economic Forum, with various agenda councils related to climate change, water and urban sustainability,
the Global Compact, and initiatives such as Transition Towns and the
Dutch action organisation Urgenda. The real question is how these
largely bottom-up initiatives can ultimately be channeled and
consolidated into lasting change. Otherwise, these noteworthy
initiatives will end up being little more than repetitive meetings where
good ideas are presented, ideas that, in the absence of institutional
adjustments, cannot compete with the mainstream way of doing things and,
hence, remain in their niches.2
2.3. Reflection: Can a Resource Revolution be Realized Without Absolute Scarcity as an Incentive?
Section 2.2 indicates
that creating a trajectory of radical change to a resource-efficient
society is no easy matter. Market-based and top-down approaches both
require a government that is legitimized to enforce change – either in
the form of creating market-based instruments and incentives or
regulation. Bottom-up initiatives either must become winners in a market
via a more or less autonomous innovation process,
or at some point get enough policy support to enforce implementation,
to avoid dying out in their niches. Creating such levels of policy
support is difficult and time consuming – interests diverge (Nelkin, 1984), beliefs about what is desirable or not differ (Sabatier, 1987), and some discourses are more dominant than others (Hajer, 2005). Powers between actor coalitions that represent these interests, beliefs and discourses are unevenly distributed (Sabatier and Jenkins-Smitch, 1993).
All this hampers sustainability transitions in general, including that
to a radically more resource efficient society. In the resources domain,
the case for resource efficiency is still mainly made to point at
possible economic win-wins (saving resources saves money), or that
resource-efficiency and circularity are an answer to resource scarcity and price volatility of resources (e.g. Ellen Macarthur Foundation (EMF), 2012, Bastein et al., 2013, World Business Council for Sustainable Development (WBCSD), 2016).
It
is however questionable whether the resource scarcity argument will
drive a radical change to resource-efficiency in the near future.3Table 1, based on an evaluation of Tukker (2013), suggests the following:
- a)
- Fossil energy materials. Given the climate challenge there is in principle a need for a radical reduction in their use, or, rather, the impacts of their use, with around a factor 10 reduction in carbon emissions required by 2050. This radical reduction however will only take place if enough political will materialises to really embark on strong and radical climate policies (International Energy Agency, 2016, Shell, 2016). Even despite the COP21 in Paris it is questionable if this will happen. It is further unlikely that absolute scarcity of fossil energy will become a bottleneck in the next few decades, significant amounts of coal, oil and (shale) gas being still available (McGlade and Ekins, 2015).
- b)
- Building and construction materials. Apart from materials that during their production create significant emissions of carbon (e.g. cement, steel, aluminium), there is no clear sign that resource or emission constraints will lead to a need to limit their use. Localised problems in e.g. densely populated areas apart, they are abundant.4 Any pressure on the use of materials such as cement, steel and aluminium seems most likely to come from climate policies, rather than from a greater desire for resource efficiency.
- c)
- Metal ores and industrial minerals. Here we encounter a very mixed situation, where some materials may indeed see absolute scarcity in the next decades, but where in most cases supply disruptions are caused by geopolitical factors or market instabilities rather than real scarcity.5 In such cases, simply learning better how to manage a market characterised by uncertainties in future demand and long lead times for opening mines, and dealing with geopolitical factors, can reduce many of the problems that exist today.
- d)
- Biotic materials, in relation to land and water use. The extraction of biotic materials is mainly limited by water and land use constraints in relation to biodiversity impacts. Population growth, diet changes and the use of biofuels all are likely to lead to the need for a higher production of biomass in future. Without efficiency improvements, this will lead to pressure on land use, biodiversity loss, and a water shortageof 30% by 2030 (e.g. Water Resources Group, 2009, Nature, 2010). These sources however also suggest such problems can be overcome by a Factor 2 improvement of land and water-efficiency by 2050, or 2% per year. While this certainly is a challenge, it is probably one that can be realized by incremental rather than radical innovations and changes.
Type of resource | Fraction of global resource extraction | Basis for planetary limits | Potential limit | Reference |
---|---|---|---|---|
Fossil fuels | 20% | Absolute scarcity CO2 emission targets | EU greenhouse gas (GHG) targets (20-20-20 or 30% reduction by 2020) Scientific targets (> 80% reduction by 2050) | International Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), 2007, International Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), 2013, Meinshausen et al. (2009). |
Metal ores and industrial minerals | 10% | Absolute scarcity (varies by metal). Most metal ores need high levels of energy to be transformed, implying a ‘linkage’ to CO2emission targets and energy constraints | Focus on 14 critical raw materials identified in the Raw Materials Initiative. Changes in energy and mobility infrastructure (solar cells, batteries) determine future criticality | EC (2014b). For linkages with energy use, see Graedel and Van der Voet (2010). |
Non-metallic minerals (mainly building materials) | 40% | With the possible exception of sand, absolute scarcity seems irrelevant, except in densely populated areas where space for mining for these minerals is limited. | Implicit targets for non-metallic minerals that need high levels of energy in their production (e.g., cement, ceramics) and linkages to land use targets (e.g. soil sealing) | For linkages: e.g. Hanle et al. (2006) |
Biomass, in relation to land and water use | 30% | Maximum human appropriation of net primary production of biomass (HANPP), the available bioproductive land taking into account reservation for nature areas, and the renewable supply of water by region | Currently, 30%–35% of available biomass is extracted by humans. Target may be stabilization or minor growth. As for land use which is dominated by agriculture, there is conflicting information whether efficiency growth in agriculture will avoid land shortage in future. For water, a global ‘water gap’ of 30% is expected in 2030 | Vitousek et al. (1986), Haberl et al. (2007). Erb et al. (2009) OECD/FAO (2009) Nature (2010); Hoekstra and Chapagain (2007) Water resources group/McKinsey (2009). |
Although
there are obviously linkages between these resource categories, such as
that a more productive agriculture may require more energy input (Graedel and van der Voet, 2010),
the overall picture is that in the next decades scarcity will not be a
transition driver. Yet, since transitions take a long time, and
resources on Earth are indeed finite and may become scarce in the long
term, it may be useful to start working immediately on a transition to
radically more efficient resource use and a circular economy. A key
question, however, is how to do this when for many resources there seems
still ample scope to enhance production, and a critical mass and
legitimation of government for interventions other than in support of
cost reduction and enhanced competitiveness is lacking.
3. Dimensions for Analyzing Sustainability and Resource-Efficiency Concepts
3.1. Introduction
In the past, various authors have reviewed strategies that can guide a transition of our economic system of production and consumption towards a higher level of eco-efficiency,
resource efficiency and/or sustainability. In doing so, they have
proposed various key dimensions that can characterize such strategies.
This section reviews a number of such classifications, most notably from
the EU Eco-Innovation Observatory (Eco-Innovation Observatory, 2013), the OECD's work on eco-innovation (OECD, 2009), work of GWS on ‘Green growth’ strategies (GWS, 2013) and others (Hopwood et al., 2005, Tukker and Tischner, 2006).
In this analysis, we did not strive for a comprehensive review of all
classifications that may have been developed in the past. We did however
use the classifications that have been developed under assignments of
dominant policy actors, such as the German government, the EU and the
OECD, which we think is an appropriate sample to build our own
classification upon. We review these classifications in Section 3.2 and on this basis, develop our own classification in Section 3.3.
3.2. Dimensions Used in Earlier Studies
The first conceptualization we show is one developed by the European Eco-Innovation Observatory (2013). They use this to classify eco-innovation concepts such as industrial symbiosis, product improvements,
and extended producer responsibility. This conceptualisation discerns
two dimensions: the degree of change (system adaptation, or systems
transformation), and the scope of the system that is changed (system
components such as individual technologies or products; sub-systems such
as value chains;
or transformations of major parts of society, such as the energy
system, the urban system). This then leads to a classification as in Fig. 1, discerning four quadrants: incremental innovation, radical change, system adaptation and transformative system innovation.
A second classification of eco-innovations is given by the OECD (2009) in its Sustainable Manufacturing and Eco-Innovation Synthesis Report (see Fig. 2).
The x-axis resembles very much a parameter that is also used by the EU
Eco-innovation observatory: modification of existing systems or creation
of fully new systems. The y-axis however looks at elements of the
system that is targeted, rather than the scope of change of the system: products and
processes, organisation and marketing methods, or institutions. The
OECD uses this to identify if change is mainly of a technical or
non-technical nature. (See Fig. 3.)
Lombardi et al. (2011) use a classification of Hopwood et al. (2005) to
organise various views on sustainable development. Again, the x-axis
gives the level of transformation required, but focuses on the
environmental aspect of sustainability only. The y-axis covers the level
of importance given to human well-being and equality, and is hence
clearly of a socio-economic nature.
Tukker and Tischner (2006) identify
five main intervention points along the production-consumption chain
that each can improve the environmental performance of our economic
system. In short it concerns (cf Tukker et al., 2010)
- •
- 1: End of pipe/reducing emission factors
- •
- 2a: Enhancing productivity of existing systems - greening production processes and products 2b: Enhancing productivity via system innovations – similar to 2a, but creating ‘Factor X’ improvements via system innovation of products and processes;
- •
- 3: Intensifying the use of products, e.g. via product-service systems
- •
- 4: Enhancing immaterial consumption/less impact intensive expenditure;
- •
These
improvement strategies now can be plotted on two axes: whether they
address production or consumption and whether they are radical or
incremental (see Fig. 4).
Finally, GWS (2013) developed a classification of about two dozen ‘Green Growth’ strategies. They used about 16 guiding questions related to (a) environmental, economic and
social impacts, (b) possible structural economic change, (c)
underestimated future welfare impacts and (d) supportive institutional
foundations and political constellations. The answers on these questions allowed them to map each concept in a three dimensional framework that discerns an economic, environmental, and social axis, reflecting the extent to which each concept emphasises economic growth, the viability of ecosystems, and the social quality of societies.
3.3. Evaluation Dimensions Used in this Paper
When
comparing the evaluative frameworks discussed in the former section,
the following can be observed. The Eco-Innovation Observatory uses as
dimensions the Scope of change (system components or systems) and the
Degree of change (in terms of incremental and radical). The OECD again
uses Scope of change but then different system elements as targets.
Tukker and Tischner also use the Scope of change as parameter,
distinguishing between production and consumption, next to the Degree of
change (incremental and radical). Hopwood et al. use a social and
environmental dimension in combination with Degree of change. The GWS
classification is somewhat more complex, with the Degree of change along
each of the environmental, social and economic dimensions.
As
the GWS study indicates it is not difficult to end up with dozens of
criteria in respect of which new concepts with regard to resource
efficiency can be evaluated. A drawback of using many criteria is that
one easily loses oversight. We hence prefer to reduce the number of
criteria or parameters to a maximum of three. On the basis of the above
we decided that for the analysis in this paper at least the following
dimensions are relevant, and propose to use a 3-point scale to define
positions on these dimensions:
- •
- Scope of change
This plays a role in virtually all classification systems discussed in Section 3.2,
and seems also relevant given the long list of concepts mentioned in
the introduction. Some concepts focus on parts of the value chain, such
as responsible mining. Others aim at transforming whole systems. We
propose to classify initiatives in one of the following three
categories, which we will later use as ranked levels in the evaluation:
- •
- Scope is a specific industry sector (e.g. mining)
- •
- Scope is a value chain
- •
- Scope is societal system or large (sub)-systems thereof (e.g. food, energy, mobility)
- •
- Ambition with regard to the (paradigmatic) degree of change
This
resembles the degree of change found in many of the classification
systems listed above, but deliberately adds the adjective ‘paradigmatic’
to it. Currently the sustainability discussion in general and the
resource efficiency discussion in particular is often still framed in
the utilitarian, economic rationality that has dominated Western society
since enlightenment and the industrial revolution.
Many concepts simply still adhere to this existing paradigm. Other
concepts however see the existing paradigm as a root cause of the
sustainability problem, and hence argue that an upheaval in values,
institutions, etc. is essential, towards a direction that some have
dubbed a ‘Buddhist Economics’ that is focused on human development, economic processes at a smaller and more regional scale, etc. (Schumacher, 1973).
This goes significantly further than the differentiation between
incremental and radical change, which is often just focused on technical
aspects. We see further that within the existing paradigm of
utilitarian, economic rationality of use of nature there is a
differentiation between approaches that emphasise predominantly the
business opportunities and benefits for being resource efficient – the
role of authorities then simply is to remove market failures -
and approaches that see also a threat to public goods – with
authorities then having a role of protecting them. This leads then to
the following three categories which we will later use as ranked levels
in the evaluation:
- •
- No paradigmatic change, focus on market-based solutions
- •
- Intermediate paradigmatic change in the sense that there is a recognition of the ‘public good’ character of resource-related problems that need government intervention
- •
- Fundamental paradigmatic change, the concept clearly calls for a revolution in our economic system, related values, institutions, etc.
- •
- Explicit Attention to the Plausibility of Pathways of Change
This dimension is in fact fully absent from most of the classifications reviewed in Section 3.2 –
only the GWS guiding questions include topics like the potential of
institutions and political constellations. Our discussion in chapter 2
shows it is essential to have an understanding how far-reaching, radical
changes can be actively fostered. Major historical changes like a
‘resource revolution’ do not happen automatically. Particularly with
regard to radical, paradigmatic changes, Kuhn (1962) already
noted that these are not frequent and only happen when the existing
paradigm is about to become untenable. Concepts that respond to
specified driving forces, or provide a clear pathway or formula as to
how change must come about hence have value over concepts that don't.
Factors that may help or hinder shaping a ‘resource revolution’ include a
proven (physical or geopolitical) scarcity of resources; technological
momentum, social momentum, and institutional momentum. We would propose
the following three categories to classify concepts on this dimension
which we will later use as ranked levels in the evaluation:
- •
- The concept ignores important factors that make the proposed change difficult or impossible to achieve, or is fully silent on the pathway of change;
- •
- The concept only shows vaguely why change is needed or via what mechanisms it could occur
- •
- The concept is clear in identifying pathways for change
4. Assessment of Sustainability and Resource-Efficiency Concepts
4.1. Materials and Methods
For the purpose of this study, an inventory was
made of around 30 widely used sustainability concepts that include a
more efficient use of resources in their scope. The ambition was to
cover a large sample of widely used concepts, rather than to be fully
comprehensive. We based ourselves amongst others on listings in the
literature from the former section from which we derived the dimensions
on which the concepts should be evaluated (e.g. Hopwood et al., 2005, OECD, 2009Lombardi et al. (2011), Eco-Innovation Observatory (2013) and GWS (2013)).
The list was reviewed and complemented by 5–6 members of the study team
from 5 different institutes in 4 different countries. While the final
list inevitably is somewhat arbitrary, this procedure ensures it does
contain a large number of the most used concepts.
For
each concept reviewed, a short literature analysis was done, resulting
in a one-to–two- page description of the concept on the following
aspects:
- 1.
- The concept in brief: main aim, origins/authors, and history/impact
- 2.
- Scope of change
- 3.
- Ambition of change
- 4.
- Pathway of change
- 5.
Each
concept was assessed on the three dimensions discussed in the former
section: scope of change, paradigmatic degree of change, and
plausibility of pathways of change. For this, a simple scoring table was
developed as depicted in Table 2, simply using the three levels defined in Section 3.3, giving a − 1 in case of a low score, a 0 in case of a medium score, and a + 1 in case of a high score.
Low (− 1) | Medium (0) | High (+ 1) | |
---|---|---|---|
Scope of change | One specific industry | Various parts of value chains | Societal (sub) systems |
Paradigmatic degree of change | Focus on market-based solutions | Recognition of ‘public goods’ and related right of government to act in public interest | Seeks an alternative for the utilitarian and rational economic approach to life and nature |
Plausibility of pathways of change | Ignores factors making change difficult/does not discuss change | Explains at best conceptually factors supporting change | Explicit and plausible discussion of pathways of change |
The
descriptions are provided as Supplementary information (SI) to this
paper. Each description ends with a scoring table in which the cells in Table 2 reflecting
the score for the reviewed concept were made grey. For the analysis,
the mapping was performed and cross-checked by again the 5–6
aforementioned people in the study team. Differences in opinion on
mappings were circulated and discussed in a phone meeting, in which a
consensus mapping was reached. One can always debate if such qualitative
scoring approaches using expert panels are sufficiently robust.
However, it may be noted that the panel used comprised scientists with
rather different scientific and cultural backgrounds, and the consensus
mapping was concluded without disagreement. While acknowledging that
assessment procedures like the one applied always have some residual
level of subjectivity, the results are in our view sufficiently robust
to be used in the analysis performed.
4.2. Results of the Assessment
The results of the scoring procedure are summarized in Table 3. Of course for realising real radical changes towards for resource-efficiency one would like to see concepts that score high (+ 1) on all aspects. Radical changes towards resource-efficiency must after all
- a)
- Address societal sub-systems rather than single value chainsor an individual industry; the volume of change otherwise simply will be too low;
- b)
- Have a high level of paradigmatic degree of change;
- c)
- Have a high plausibility of pathways of change, since otherwise the concept gives no clue as to how change will happen.
No | Scope of change | Paradigmatic degree | Plausibility of paths | |
---|---|---|---|---|
1 | Industrial ecology | 1 | − 1 | 0 |
2 | Industrial symbiosis | 0 | − 1 | 0 |
3 | Waste prevention | 0 | 0 | 1 |
4 | Extended Producer Responsibility (EPR) | 0 | − 1 | 1 |
5 | Supply chain management | 0 | − 1 | 1 |
6 | Leasing society | 1 | 1 | − 1 |
7 | Ecological economics | 1 | 1 | 0 |
8 | Natural step | 1 | 1 | 0 |
9 | Weak sustainability | 1 | − 1 | 1 |
10 | Strong sustainability | 1 | 0 | 1 |
11 | Small is beautiful | 1 | 1 | 0 |
12 | Eco innovation | 1 | 0 | 1 |
13 | Transition management | 1 | 0 | 0 |
14 | Green growth | 1 | − 1 | 1 |
15 | Green economy | 1 | 0 | 1 |
16 | Beyond GDP | 1 | − 1 | 0 |
17 | Cleaner production | 0 | − 1 | 1 |
18 | Eco-efficiency | 0 | − 1 | 1 |
19 | Decoupling/(increased) resource efficiency | 0 | 0 | 0 |
20 | Pollution prevention pays | 0 | − 1 | 1 |
21 | Sustainable consumption and production | 1 | 0 | 0 |
22 | Product service systems | 1 | 1 | 0 |
23 | Circular economy | 1 | − 1 | 0 |
24 | 3Rs (reduce, re-use, recycle) | 1 | − 1 | 0 |
25 | De-growth | 1 | 1 | 0 |
26 | Resilience, safe operating space | 1 | 1 | 0 |
27 | Hannover principles | − 1 | 1 | − 1 |
28 | BoPa business models | 0 | − 1 | 0 |
29 | Leapfrogging | 0 | 0 | 0 |
30 | Slow food, transition towns | 1 | 1 | 0 |
- a
- Base of the Pyramid (BoP) business models focus on transforming the informal dysfunctional markets, and therefore the whole economic system, of the poorest socio-economic group.
Against
this background, we presented the results in two other tables, i.e. one
that lists all concepts scoring + 1 on paradigmatic degree of change
(all but one of which score + 1 on the scope of change as well), and one
that lists all concepts that score + 1 on plausibility of pathways of
change. Table 3, Table 4, Table 5 lead to the following, somewhat sobering findings:
- a)
- There is not any concept scoring + 1 on all aspects. Or, in other words, there is not any concept that aims at changes at societal level, that is radical and paradigmatic, and that at the same time provides a clear and plausible pathway of change.
- b)
- We see further that by far the most concepts that have a credible/plausible pathway of change in fact do not aim at a high level of paradigmatic change. Indeed, most concepts (extended producer responsibility, supply chain management, green growth, cleaner production, pollution prevention pays and eco-efficiency) simply assume that changes will be driven by win-win concepts, while it is well-known that changes based on such drivers tend to be incremental.
- c)
- Conversely, we see that concepts aiming at a high level of paradigmatic change at best have a conceptual explanation of factors that might bring this change about.
Scope of change | Paradigmatic degree | Plausibility of paths | |
---|---|---|---|
Waste prevention | 0 | 0 | 1 |
Extended producer responsibility | 0 | − 1 | 1 |
Supply chain management | 0 | − 1 | 1 |
Weak sustainability | 1 | − 1 | 1 |
Strong sustainability | 1 | 0 | 1 |
Eco innovation | 1 | 0 | 1 |
Green growth | 1 | − 1 | 1 |
Green economy | 1 | 0 | 1 |
Cleaner production | 0 | − 1 | 1 |
Eco-efficiency | 0 | − 1 | 1 |
Pollution prevention pays | 0 | − 1 | 1 |
Scope of change | Paradigmatic degree | Plausibility of paths | |
---|---|---|---|
Ecological economics | 1 | 1 | 0 |
Natural step | 1 | 1 | 0 |
Small is beautiful | 1 | 1 | 0 |
Product-service systems | 1 | 1 | 0 |
De-growth | 1 | 1 | 0 |
Resilience, safe operating space | 1 | 1 | 0 |
Slow food, transition towns | 1 | 1 | 0 |
Leasing society | 1 | 1 | − 1 |
Hannover principles | − 1 | 1 | − 1 |
It
therefore seems that all the concepts analysed in fact just managed to
be convincing on one or two of the three aspects relevant for
far-reaching change.
4.3. Implications
While
as discussed there may be dispute about the individual scores in the
tables provided, this overall finding is in fact very much in line with a
message system innovation and transition scholars have conveyed for
decades. Radical and paradigmatic change implies a shift away from
existing socio-economic trajectories, the related infrastructure and sunk costs,
routines, and hence also a shift to new parties dominating the system.
Resistance to such change is hence significant, as exemplified by e.g.
the almost continuous failure of sustainability summits like Rio + 20 (2012), the COPs in Copenhagen (2009), Durban (2011). ‘New concepts’ like Degrowth, Ecological economics and
Small is beautiful hence may point at new ideas for organising society
in a sustainable or resource-efficient manner, but simply having an
appealing idea – even if embraced by various groups in society - is
nothing like sufficient to foster revolutions that
can overcome the resisting powers mentioned earlier. This suggests
that, in line with insights from the transition management approach, the
existing system and parties with power in it must already be under
significant pressure before they ‘crack’ and a real revolution becomes
possible.
5. Discussion and Conclusions
This paper evaluated about 30 concepts supportive of the resource efficiency agenda, such as degrowth, the circular economy, green growth, and cleaner production.
For each concept our study analysed whether it addressed a small or
main part of society, whether the proposed change would be incremental
or radical, and whether it provided a credible pathway for pursuing this
change. Our research found that concepts either provide
- •
- a vision of far-reaching change, but fail to provide a plausible and credible pathway of how to realise this change, or
- •
- a credible, win-win pathway for change, that upon a closer look is likely to result in incremental change rather than radical change.
This
finding is consistent with literature on transitions and system
innovations. Radical and paradigmatic changes move away from existing socio-economic regimes and the related infrastructure, sunk costs and
routines, and the dominant parties maintaining such regimes. Resistance
to far-reaching change is hence usually significant since existing
regime players often have no, or a different position in a radically
changed future. And, as analysed in chapter 2 (Table 1),
autonomous developments are unlikely to force such actors to embark on a
‘resource revolution’. Drastic reduction of the use of fossil energy carriers will rely on strong climate policies. To meet the growing need for biomass without
a rise of land and water use the challenge is an efficiency improvement
of about 2% per year until 2050. For non-metallic minerals and metals
the situation is differentiated – if they are on criticality lists, in
most cases this is due to supply concentration problems rather than
absolute scarcity (EC, 2014b).
A business as usual scenario for resource use will have plenty of
challenges including balancing resource supply and demand, managing volatility, and managing emission and waste problems related to resource extraction, but it is unclear if this will provide sufficient legitimacy for radical resource reduction policies.
Our
contribution is hence mainly that we show all researched concepts fail
to provide an answer to this crucial implementation question (or do not
need to answer it, since the concept only aims at incremental change),
Solid research into via which pathways radical changes to
resource-efficiency can be fostered in the absence of scarcity or
inherent unbearable pollution as a driving factor is hence essential.
Creating yet another appealing concept that fails to explain how to
overcome powers that resist radical change is useless.
Of course this is not at all to say that resource efficiency policies are pointless. UNEP, 2016, UNEP, 2017 shows that there are many opportunities for both economic and
environmental benefits from the intelligent implementation of such
policies. Moreover, resource efficiency policies can complement other
environmental policies, such as those that reduce carbon emissions. For instance, UNEP, 2016(p.33)
shows that a strong policy on resource efficiency could reduce global
resource use by 17%, and increase global GDP by 1.6%, by 2050 compared
to current trends. A combination of a strong climate policy with a
strong resource efficiency policy could reduce global carbon emissions
by 63% from 2015 levels, and those in G7 countries by 74% from 2015 levels – sufficient to meet the 2 °C
global average temperature target endorsed by the Paris Agreement at
COP21 in December 2015. It is also uncontested that on the longer term,
humanity is probably better off when moving towards a resource-efficient
and circular economy. The Earth and its resources are finite.
Continuing economic growth on
a time span of over a century or more seems only viable by designing
societal systems in such a way that resources are kept in closed loops
(as long as this does not need significant energy or other resource
inputs), or that they are based on massively abundant materials.
Furthermore, as discussed the UNEP, 2016, UNEP, 2017 report
shows that if policies for radical increases in resource efficiency
could be implemented, they would generate greater environmental
improvements at lower, and perhaps no, net cost for society as a whole.
The
problem lies in the fact that to make this happen without directly
present scarcity drivers, on the short term such change becomes a matter
of societal and/or political will. The example of the climate issue
shows us that such political will, even in the face of convincing
scientific evidence of the urgent need for change, is anything but easy
to generate, although the Paris Agreement at COP21 provides some
evidence that policy makers may at last be taking the scientific
evidence seriously. But in the absence of comparable evidence for the
immediate need for radical increases in resource efficiency, and despite
the evidence that many such increases could be economically and
environmentally beneficial for society now, none of the concepts that
have been created to promote resource efficiency seem to have the
transformative power to significantly increase its rate of take-up. The uncertainties, policy makers' lack of willingness to intervene strongly in markets, and resistance lobbying from
those who themselves as likely to be losers from attempts to promote
resource efficiency, have to date been enough to prevent serious
progress on this issue.
There are four possible outcomes to this situation, expressed here in terms of the analytical framework described earlier.
The first is that those advocating radical increases in resource efficiency (for example, those in Table 5)
will be able to postulate a credible and plausible pathway for its
achievement that allows it to be pursued at scale in practice. The
second is that incremental changes (for example, those in Table 4) will be implemented in a way that opens up economic, social,
political or technological space for such changes to be pursued more
radically, or for more radical changes to be adopted. The third possible
outcome is that real physical resource scarcity or
scarcities, currently largely unforeseen, will arise, that will enforce
radical increases in resource efficiency. A variant of this outcome is
that, notwithstanding current successes in decoupling such impacts from
resource use to some extent, the socio-environmental impacts of
continuation of current trends in resource use (e.g. conflicts about
mining and waste disposal; conflicts about water and land use etc.)
become more and more unbearable, also leading to radical increases in
resource efficiency. A fourth possible outcome is that approaches based
largely on ‘business-as-usual’ will allow such scarcities as arise to be
addressed within the current paradigm, such that radical change proves
to be unnecessary.
The
resource efficiency agenda is hence at a crossroads. In the domain of
climate policy, policy makers increasingly reject outcome 4 in favor of
some combination of outcomes 1 and 2, in view of compelling scientific
evidence of dangerous outcomes in a business as usual scenario (outcome
3). Attitudes to policy making on resource efficiency are still largely
based on outcome 4. This leaves only the hope that such attempts at
outcomes 1 and 2 as actually occur may make more radical approaches more
acceptable before outcome 3 causes the significant economic and social
disruption that some now fear.
Acknowledgments
The
authors like to acknowledge those who helped review many of the
concepts discussed here: Teresa Domenech (UCL), Jill Jäger and Franziska
Hartwig (SERI), and René Kemp (UNU Merit, ICIS). The paper was written
in the context of the EU funded project ENV.2012.6.3-2 - Policy Options for a Resource-Efficient Economy, Grant Agreement no. 308371. The authors have no competing interests to declare.
References
- Bastein et al., 2013
- T. Bastein, E. Roelofs, E. Rietveld, A. HoogendoornOpportunities for a Circular Economy in the NetherlandsTNO, Delft, Netherlands (2013)available fromaccessed 21 May 2017
- Dahlstrom and Ekins, 2005
- K. Dahlstrom, P. EkinsEco-efficiency trends in the UK steel and aluminum industriesJ. Ind. Ecol., 9 (4) (2005), pp. 171-188
- EC, 2005
- ECCommunication “Thematic Strategy on the Sustainable use of Natural Resources”COM(2005) 670 Final, European Commission, Brussels, Belgium (2005)
- EC, 2014a
- ECCommunication “Towards a Circular Economy: A zero Waste Programme for Europe”COM/2014/0398 Final, European Commission, Brussels, Belgium (2014)
- EC, 2014b
- ECReport on Critical Raw Materials for the EU. Report of the Ad hoc Working Group on Defining Critical Raw MaterialsEC, DG ENTR, Brussels (2014)Available fromaccessed 8 May 2016
- Eco-innovation observatory, 2013
- Eco-innovation observatory, 2013 Europe in Transition: Paving the Way to a Green Economy Through Eco-innovation. Annual Report 2012, January 2013. Available from http://www.eco-innovation.eu/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=634:new-annual-report-2012-now-available&catid=24:announcements.
- Ellen Macarthur Foundation (EMF), 2012
- Ellen Macarthur Foundation (EMF)Towards the Circular Economy Vol. 1: An Economic and Business Rationale for an Accelerated TransitionEMF (2012)Available fromaccessed 21 May 2017
- Ellen Macarthur Foundation (EMF), 2015
- Ellen Macarthur Foundation (EMF)Growth within: A Circular Economy Vision for a Competitive EuropeEMF (2015)Available fromaccessed 21 May 2017
- Elzen et al., 2004
- B. Elzen, F.W. Geels, K. Green (Eds.), System Innovation and the Transition to Sustainability: Theory, Evidence and Policy, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham (2004)
- Erb et al., 2009
- Karl-Heinz Erb, Helmut Haberl, Fridolin Krausmann, Christian Lauk, Christoph Plutzar, Julia K. Steinberger, Christoph Müller, Alberte Bondeau, Katharina Waha, Gudrun PollackEating the Planet: Feeding and Fuelling the World Sustainably, Fairly and Humanely – A Scoping Study. Commissioned by Compassion in World Farming and Friends of the Earth UKInstitute of Social Ecology and PIK Potsdam, Vienna (2009)Social Ecology Working Paper No. 116
- European Environment Agency (EEA), 2015
- European Environment Agency (EEA)The European Environment. State and Outlook 2015. Synthesis ReportEuropean Environment Agency, Copenhagen, Denmark (2015)
- Geels, 2002
- F.W. GeelsTechnological transitions as evolutionary reconfiguration processes: a multi-level perspective and a case-studyRes. Policy, 31.8 (9) (2002), pp. 1257-1274
- Tukker and Tischner, 2006
- A. Tukker, U. TischnerNew Business for Old EuropeGreenleaf Publishing, Sheffield, UK (2006)
- Tukker et al., 2010
- A. Tukker, M. Cohen, K. Hubacek, O. MontImpacts of household consumption and options for changeJ. Ind. Ecol., 14 (1) (2010)
- Tukker et al., 2013
- A. Tukker, T. Domenech, P. Ekins, J. Jäger, F. Hartwig, R. KempSynthesis of new conceptsPOLFREE Report, D2 (2013), p. 1available at
- UNEP, 2011
- UNEPDecoupling natural resource use and environmental impacts from economic growthM. Fischer-Kowalski, M. Swilling, E.U. von Weizsäcker, Y. Ren, Y. Moriguchi, W. Crane, F. Krausmann, N. Eisenmenger, S. Giljum, P. Hennicke, P. Romero Lankao, A. Siriban Manalang (Eds.), A Report of the Working Group on Decoupling to the International Resource Panel, UNEP, Paris (2011)
- UNEP, 2014a
- UNEPDecoupling 2: technologies, opportunities and policy optionsE.U. Von Weizsäcker, J. de Larderel, K. Hargroces, C. Hudson, M. Smith, M.Rodrigues (Eds.), A Report of the Working Group on Decoupling to the International Resources Panel, UNEP, Paris (2014)
- UNEP, 2014b
- UNEPSand: Rarer Than One ThinksUNEP Global Environmental Alert Service (2014)
- UNEP, 2016
- UNEP (2016) Resource efficiency: potential and economic implications, (lead authors Ekins, P. and Hughes, N.), Summary for Policy Makers of a Report to the G7 Governments From the International Resource Panel, UNEP, Paris.
- UNEP, 2017
- UNEPResource efficiency: potential and economic implicationsP. Ekins, N. Hughes, et al. (Eds.), Report to the G7 Governments From the International Resource Panel, UNEP, Paris (2017)
- Vitousek et al., 1986
- P. Vitousek, P. Ehrlich, A. Ehrlich, P. MatsonHuman appropriation of the products of photosynthesisBioscience, Vol. 36 (6) (1986)
- Water Resources Group, 2009
- Water Resources GroupCharting Our Water Future. Economic Frameworks to Inform Decision-makingMcKinsey & Company (2009)
- World Business Council for Sustainable Development (WBCSD), 1999
- World Business Council for Sustainable Development (WBCSD)Sustainability through the Market. Executive BriefWorld Business Council for Sustainable Development, Geneva, Switzerland(1999)
- World Business Council for Sustainable Development (WBCSD), 2016
- World Business Council for Sustainable Development (WBCSD)Unlocking More Value with Fewer Resources. A Practical Guide to the Circular EconomyWBCSD Leadership Programme. WBCSD, Geneva, Switzerland (2016)
- World Economic Forum, 2014
- World Economic ForumTowards the Circular Economy: Accelerating the Scale-up Across Global Supply ChainsWEF, Geneva (2014)available fromaccessed 21 May 2017
- ☆
- This paper derives from a project that received funding from the European Union’s Seventh Programme for research, technological development and demonstration under grant agreement No 308371.
- 1
- As discussed by Tukker and Butter (2007), these approaches reflect the so-called individualist, hierarchist and egalitarian perspectives in Cultural Theory, see e.g. Thompson et al. (1990), and further discussion in Tukker et al., 2013
- 2
- Even those who claim that we should build less on top-down agreements and foster and trust the ‘energetic society’ more (Hajer, 2011) acknowledge that there is a role for authorities: ‘Authorities should give clarity (..). Then investors will dare to invest. Offer them certainty. Create new green accounting rules. Abolish subsidies that prevent innovation and keep us in the 20th century’. Maarten Hajer, column based on a presentation during the meeting ‘Rio aan de Maas’ (Rio on the Meuse’), ‘Rio as global fair’, 30 May 2012, as published on http://www.pbl.nl/node/55684 (accessed 14 August 2012).
- 3
- One reviewer suggested that impacts of resource use would create the driver for radical changes to resource efficiency. We question this argument. In Europe for instance, resource use has grown significantly in the last decades, while apart from carbon emissions most environmental pressures were reduced (EEA, 2015). Even in cases where higher resource use almost inevitably leads to higher environmental pressures, such as in the case of climate change in relation to fossil fuel use, policy legitimation and action took decades to develop. It is hence questionable that pointing at the impacts of resource use will provide sufficient policy legitimation to embark on a resource efficiency policy that is radical and may hurt interests of the current mainstream actors.
- 5
- A clear example of this is provided by Rare Earth Elements. In 2002 low prices of Chinese mines next to environmental problems led to closure of the only Western mine left, the US Mountain Pass mine, that had dominated supply for decades. The total value of REE materials mined annually was < 1 billion US$ at the time. Although demand was expected to rise, the level to which was uncertain, and the (minor) mining companies in the West simply could not take the risk nor attract the capital to anticipate this new demand by opening new mines. Around 2007, China foresaw that it needed most of the nationally mined REE for its own industry, and started to reduce exports which led subsequently to a supply crisis in the West – high price volatility, price hikes, etc. Only then the West scrambled to see if new mines could be opened on the shortest possible notice – which given the long lead time to open mines would still take years. Given the fact that proven reserves of REE that can be mined economically are 800 times annual use, this crisis clearly has nothing to do with scarcity (Tukker, 2014).
© 2017 Published by Elsevier B.V.
F.W. GeelsTechnological Transitions, A Co-evolutionary and Socio-Technical Analysis
Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK (2005)
T.E. Graedel, E. van der Voet (Eds.), Linkages of Sustainability, MIT Press, Cambridge (2010)
GWSGWS
Discussion Paper 2013/1 ISSN 1867–7290: Synopsis of Approaches to
Welfare and of Green Growth Concepts Currently under Discussion
GWS, Osnabrück, Germany (2013)
H. Haberl, K.-H. Erb, F. Krausmann, V. Gaube, A. Bondeau, C.Plutzar, S. Gingrich, W. Lucht, M. Fischer-KowalskiQuantifying and mapping the human appropriation of net primary production in earth's terrestrial ecosystems
Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci. USA, 104 (2007)
M. HajerThe Politics of Environmental Discourse: Ecological Modernization and the Policy Process
Clarendon press, Oxford, UK (2005)
M. HajerThe Energetic Society. In Search of a Governance Philosophy for a Clean Economy
PBL Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency, The Hague (2011)
L. Hanle, P. Maldonado, E. Onuma, M. Tichy, H.G. van OssIPCC guidelines for national greenhouse gas inventories
Volume 3: Industrial Processes and Product Use (2006)
(Geneva, Switzerland)
A.Y. Hoekstra, A.K. ChapagainGlobalization of Water: Sharing the Planet's Freshwater Resources
Blackwell Publishing, Oxford, UK (2007)
B. Hopwood, M. Mellor, G. O'BrienSustainable development: mapping different approaches
Sustain. Dev., 13 (2005), pp. 38-52
International Energy AgencyEnergy, Climate Change and Environment: 2016 Insights
IEA, Paris, France (2016)
Available from
accessed 21 May 2017
International Panel on Climate Change (IPCC)The 4th Assessment. Summary for Policy Makers. Geneva, Switzerland
(2007)
International Panel on Climate Change (IPCC)Fifth Assessment Report. Summary for Policy Makers. Geneva, Switzerland
(2013)
R. KempTransition management for sustainable consumption and production
2008
A. Tukker, M. Charter, C. Vezzoli, E. Sto, M. Munch Andersen (Eds.), System Innovation for Sustainability I. Perspectives on Radical Change to Sustainable Consumption and Production, Greenleaf Publishing, Sheffield, UK (2008)
R. Kemp, S. van den BoschTransitie-experimenten.
Praktijkexperimenten met de potentie om bij de dragen aan transities.
[Transition Experiments. Practical Experiments With the Potential to
Contribute to Transitions]. Kenniscentrum SysteemInnovaties en
Transities, p/o TNO, Delft, Netherlands
(2006)
R. Kemp, D. Loorbach, J. RotmansTransition management as a model for managing processes of co-evolution towards sustainable development
The International Journal of Sustainable Development and World Ecology, 14(1) (2007), pp. 78-91
P. KennedyThe Rise and Fall of Great Powers
Fontana Press, Hammersmith, London, UK (1988)
1988
T. KuhnThe Structure of Scientific Revolutions
The University of Chicago Press, Chicago, US (1962)
Rachel D. Lombardi, Libby Porter, Austin Barber, Chris D.F.RogersConceptualisation sustainability in UK urban regeneration: a discursive formation
Urban Stidies, 48 (2) (2011), pp. 273-296
D. LoorbachTo
Transition! Governance Panarchy in the New Transformation. Inaugural
Address Given in Shortened Form at the Occasion of Accepting the
Appointment as Professor of Socio-economic Transitions; Science and
Practice
Erasmus University Rotterdam (2014)
Available from
accessed 21 May 2017
C. McGlade, P. EkinsThe geographical distribution of fossil fuels unused when limiting global warming to 2 °C
Nature (2015), pp. 187-190
2015
Malte Meinshausen, Nicolai Meinshausen, William Hare, Sarah C.B. Raper, Katja Frieler, Reto Knutti, David J. Frame, Myles R. AllenGreenhouse-gas emission targets for limiting global warming to 2 ° C
Nature, 458 (2009), pp. 1158-1162
Ministry of the Environment (MoE)Japan's Experience in the Promotion of the 3Rs. For the Establishment of a Sound Material-Cycle Society
Ministry of the Environment, Tokyo, Japan (2006)
available from
accessed 21 May 2017
NatureThe Growing Problem
466 (7306) (2010), pp. 546-547
29 July 2010
D. NelkinControversy. Politics of Technical Decisions
(Second edition), Sage Publications, Beverly Hills/London/New Delhi (1984)
OECD and FAOOECD-FAO Agricultural Outlook 2009–2018
OECD, Paris, France (2009)
E. OstromGoverning the Commons. The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (MA) (1990)
J. Rockström, W. Steffen, K. Noone, A. Persson, F.S. Chapin, E.F. Lambin, T.M. Lenton, M. Scheffer, C. Folke, H.J. Schellnhuber, B.Nykvist, C.A. de Wit, T. Hughes, S. van der Leeuw, H. Rodhe, S. Sorlin, P.K.Snyder, R. Costanza, U. Svedin, M. Falkenmark, L. Karlberg, R.W. Corell, V.J. Fabry, J. Hansen, B. Walker, D. Liverman, K. Richardson, P. Crutzen, J.A. FoleyA safe operating space for humanity
Nature, 461 (7263) (2009), p. 472
J. Rotmans, R. Kemp, M. van AsseltMore evolution than revolution. Transition management in public policy
Foresight, 3 (1) (2001), pp. 15-31
P.A. SabatierKnowledge, policy oriented learning and policy change. An advocacy coalition framework
Knowledge, 8 (4) (1987), pp. 649-692
P.A. Sabatier, H.C. Jenkins-Smitch (Eds.), Policy Change and Learning. Ad Advocacy Coalition Approach, Westview press, Boulder/San Francisco/Oxford (1993)
F. SchumacherSmall is Beautiful: A Study of Economics as if People Mattered
Vintage Books, London (1973)
ShellA Better Life for With a Healthy Planet. Pathways to Net Zero Emissions
Shell, London, UK (2016)
Available from
accessed 21 May 2017
State Council of the People's Republic of China (State Council)Circular Economy Development Strategy and Immediate Plan of Action
Available at
in Chinese, accessed 21 May 2017
W. Steffen, K. Richardson, J. Rockström, S.E. Cornell, I. Fetzer, E.M. Bennett, R. Biggs, S.R. Carpenter, W. De Vries, C.A. De Wit, C. Folke, D. Gerten, J. Heinke, G.M. Mace, L.M. Persson, V. Ramanathan, B. Reyers, S. SörlinPlanetary boundaries: guiding human development on a changing planet
Science, 347 (736) (2015), p. 1259855
M. Thompson, R. Ellis, A. WildavskyCultural Theory
Westview Press, Boulder, Co., USA (1990)
A. TukkerKnowledge collaboration and learning by aligning global sustainability programs: reflections in the context of Rio + 20
J. Clean. Prod., 48 (2013), pp. 272-279
A. TukkerRare earth elements supply restrictions: market failures, not scarcity, hamper their current use in high-tech applications
Environ. Sci. Technol., 48 (17) (2014), pp. 9973-9974
A. Tukker, M. ButterGovernance of sustainable transitions: about the 4(0) ways to change the world
J. Clean. Prod., 15 (1) (2007), pp. 94-103
Cap comentari:
Publica un comentari a l'entrada